Be
careful what you wish for, because currencies are not abstractions we
ponder, they are commodities that serve real-world functions that
place demands on the currency as a mechanism of trade, trust, value
and risk.
The current telling of the story of
de-dollarization - the replacement of the US dollar as the global
economy's primary reserve currency with a new BRIC (Brazil, Russia,
India, China) funded reserve currency - depicts the loss of the
reserve currency as a catastrophe that will crush America.
As
delightful as this prospect may be to various audiences, once we
shift from considering a reserve currency as an abstraction to a
mechanism of trade and finance, then another outcome takes shape:
supporting a reserve currency is a burden, and lifting that burden
from the US will benefit the US and hurt mercantilist exporting
nations.
As a bonus, it will also shift the burden of
supporting a reserve currency to the BRIC participants, who will then
have to do what the US has done for decades:
1. Export their
new reserve currency in size by running vast, sustained trade
deficits, for the only way a reserve currency can function is there
is sufficient quantities of it floating around as a transparently
traded, market-priced commodity to grease trade and finance.
2.
Become the dumping ground for the world's surplus production of goods
and services as the means to run the vast, sustained trade deficits
that are the other side of exporting currency so others can use it in
global trade.
Many commentators such as Mish Shedlock and
Michael Pettis have explained these mechanisms of reserve currencies
and pointed out that being relieved of the burden of supporting the
primary reserve currency would be a great long-term benefit to the
US. I have written about Triffin's Paradox for many years, the
reality that no currency can serve both the domestic economy and the
global economy (i.e. be a reserve currency) as issuing a reserve
currency demands running trade deficits as a means of exporting
trillions of units of the currency for use by others.
In a
similar fashion, proponents of a gold-backed currency view such a
currency as an abstraction without considering the actual mechanics
of backing a currency with a tangible commodity. The currency isn't
actually "backed" by the commodity unless it can be
converted into the commodity upon demand. A currency is only "backed
by gold" if there is a conversion mechanism in which the holder
of the currency can trade the currency for the equivalent quantity of
gold.
This is the only mechanism that counts. Waving around
the phrase "backed by gold" doesn't turn a fiat currency
backed by nothing tangible into a currency backed by gold unless that
currency can be converted into gold upon demand.
So let's
think this through a bit rather than expound on abstractions. Let's
say the US loses its reserve status; nobody wants the USD any more
and so nobody will trade goods and services for dollars. That means
the US can only import as much as it exports, i.e. a trade balance.
According to the Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA), the US
exports about $3 trillion of goods and services and imports about $4
trillion. So once surplus imports can no longer be purchased with
dollars, that surplus $1 trillion in sales to mercantilist economies
like China vanishes.
Globalists love to weep and gnash their
teeth over the fact that costs of goods made in the US will be higher
than in sweatshops overseas. But globalists never consider quality,
which has been declining since globalization took the world by the
throat. Let's do the math: a poorly made imported item that only
lasts a year before it must be replaced costs $25. This item costs
$50 when manufactured in the US.
Oh, boo-hoo, right? Not so
fast. If the domestically produced item lasts 5 years, the total cost
over 5 years is $50. The total cost of the shoddy imported item is 5
X $25 or $125. The domestic product is much, much cheaper once we
expand the time frame to the entire lifetime of the product.
Who's
going to be crying real tears of anguish are all the mercantilist
economies that have dumped their surplus production in the US for
decades, as there is no alternative economy large enough to absorb
the $1 trillion in (mostly shoddy) goods and services that the US
will no longer buy.
The issuers of the new reserve currency
will have to run massive, sustained trade deficits to export enough
of their new currency to meet the demands of a reserve currency and
they'll have to let the price of the new currency float freely on
global markets, or it cannot be trusted to retain its value - a key
attribute of a reserve currency.
If this new reserve currency
is "backed by gold," then nations that pile up the new
currency in trade must be able to demand gold in exchange for the
currency, as France demanded (and received) gold in exchange for its
surplus US dollars in 1971. If the currency can't be converted into
gold, it's not a gold-backed currency. It's only backed by, well,
nothing, just like all the other fiat currencies.
Actually,
fiat currencies are backed by something: interest-paying bonds. The
higher the interest and the lower the risk profile of the bonds, the
greater demand for that currency above others with riskier profiles
and lower rates of return on the bonds.
This leads to an
irony: the US dollar will become much more valuable once it is no
longer a reserve currency as it will no longer be exported in vast
quantities. US dollars will be scarce and will thus increase in
value.
Personally, I'm in favor of competition in currencies
- the more the merrier. The more options available on a transparent
global market where all currencies are floating freely on market
supply and demand, the better for everyone.
But be careful
what you wish for, because currencies are not abstractions we ponder,
they are commodities that serve real-world functions that place
demands on the currency as a mechanism of trade, trust, value and
risk.
by
Charles Hugh Smith at oftwominds.com on April 10, 2023
No comments:
Post a Comment
Note: Only a member of this blog may post a comment.